Skip to main content

NPoS Election Algorithms

NPoS Election Algorithms

Since validators are paid almost equally in each era, it is important that the stake behind each validator is uniformly spread out. An election algorithm for Nominated Proof of Staking (NPoS) will try to optimize three metrics when computing a solution graph of nominators and validators:

  1. Maximize the total amount at stake.
  2. Maximize the stake behind the minimally staked validator.
  3. Minimize the variance of the stake in the set.
note

Sequential Phragmén, Phragmms and Star balancing are a few notable algorithms used for computing the NPoS solutions in Polkadot and Kusama.

What is the sequential Phragmén method?

The sequential Phragmén method is a multi-winner election method introduced by Edvard Phragmén in the 1890s. The quote below taken from the reference Phragmén paper sums up the purpose of the sequential Phragmén method:

note

The problem that Phragmén’s methods try to solve is that of electing a set of a given numbers of persons from a larger set of candidates. Phragmén discussed this in the context of a parliamentary election in a multi-member constituency; the same problem can, of course, also occur in local elections, but also in many other situations such as electing a board or a committee in an organization.

Validator Elections

The sequential Phragmén is one of the methods used in the Nominated Proof-of-Stake scheme to elect validators based on their own self-stake and the stake that is voted to them from nominators. It also tries to equalize the weights between the validators after each election round.

Off-Chain Phragmén

Given the large set of nominators and validators, Phragmén's method is a difficult optimization problem. Polkadot uses off-chain workers to compute the result off-chain and submit a transaction to propose the set of winners. The reason for performing this computation off-chain is to keep a constant block time of six seconds and prevent long block times at the end of each era, when the validator election takes place.

Staking Miners

The process of computing the optimal solution for NPoS election can be delegated to Staking Miners.

Council Elections

Deprecated in Polkadot OpenGov

Phragmen was used for Council elections in Governance v1.

The Phragmén method was also used in the council election mechanism. When you voted for council members, you could select up to 16 different candidates and then place a reserved bond as the weight of your vote. Phragmén would run once on every election to determine the top candidates to assume council positions and then again amongst the top candidates to equalize the weight of the votes behind them as much as possible.

What does it mean for node operators?

Phragmén is something that will run in the background and requires no extra effort from you. However, it is good to understand how it works since it means that not all the stake you've been nominated will end up on your validator after an election. Nominators are likely to nominate a few different validators that they trust to do a good job operating their nodes.

You can use this offline-phragmén tool for predicting the outcome of a validator election ahead of a new election.

Understanding Phragmén

This section explains the sequential Phragmén method in-depth and walks through examples.

Basic Phragmén

Rationale

In order to understand the Weighted Phragmén method, we must first understand the basic Phragmén method. There must be some group of candidates, a group of seats they are vying for (which is less than the size of the group of candidates), and some group of voters. The voters can cast an approval vote - that is, they can signal approval for any subset of the candidates.

The subset should be a minimum size of one (i.e., one cannot vote for no candidates) and a maximum size of one less than the number of candidates (i.e., one cannot vote for all candidates). Users are allowed to vote for all or no candidates, but this will not affect the final result, making votes of this nature meaningless.

Note that in this example, all voters are assumed to have equal say (that is, their vote does not count more or less than any other votes). The weighted case will be considered later. However, weighting can be "simulated" by having multiple voters vote for the same slate of candidates. For instance, five people voting for a particular candidate is mathematically the same as a single person with weight 5 voting for that candidate.

The particular algorithm we call here the "Basic Phragmén" was first described by Brill et al. in their paper "Phragmén’s Voting Methods and Justified Representation".

Algorithm

The Phragmén method will iterate, selecting one seat at a time, according to the following rules:

  1. Voters submit their ballots, marking which candidates they approve. Ballots will not be modified after submission.
  2. An initial load of 0 is set for each ballot.
  3. The candidate who wins the next available seat is the one where the ballots of their supporters would have the least average (mean) cost if that candidate wins.
  4. The n ballots that approved that winning candidate get 1/n added to their load.
  5. The load of all ballots that supported the winner of this round are averaged out so that they are equal.
  6. If there are any more seats, go back to step 3. Otherwise, the selection ends.

Example

Let's walk through an example with four candidates vying for three seats, and five voters.

Open Seats: 3

Candidates: A B C D L0
-------------------------
Voter V1: X 0
Voter V2: X X 0
Voter V3: X X 0
Voter V4: X X 0
Voter V5: X X X 0

In this example, we can see that voter V1 approves only of candidate B, voter V2 approves of candidates C and D, etc. Voters can approve any number of candidates between 1 and number_of_candidates - 1. An initial "load" of 0 is set for each ballot (L0 = load after round 0, i.e., the "round" before the first round). We shall see shortly how this load is updated and used to select candidates.

We will now run through an iterative algorithm, with each iteration corresponding to one "seat". Since there are three seats, we will walk through three rounds.

For the first round, the winner is simply going to be the candidate with the most votes. Since all loads are equal, the lowest average load will be the candidate with the highest n, since 1/n will get smaller as n increases. For this first example round, for instance, candidate A had only one ballot vote for them. Thus, the average load for candidate A is 1/1, or 1. Candidate C has two ballots approving of them, so the average load is 1/2. Candidate B has the lowest average load, at 1/4 and they get the first seat. Ballots loads are now averaged out, although for the first iteration, this will not have any effect.

Filled seats: 1 (B)
Open Seats: 2

Candidates: A B C D L0 L1
-----------------------------
Voter V1: X 0 1/4
Voter V2: X X 0 0
Voter V3: X X 0 1/4
Voter V4: X X 0 1/4
Voter V5: X X X 0 1/4

We are now down to candidates A, C, and D for two open seats. There is only one voter (V4) for A, with load 1/4. C has two voters, V2 and V5, with loads of 0 and 1/4. D has three voters approving of them, V2, V3, and V5, with loads of 0, 1/4, and 1/4, respectively.

If Candidate A wins, the average load would be (1/4 + 1/1) / 1, or 5/4. If candidate C wins, the average load would be ((0 + 1/2) + (1/4 + 1/2)) / 2, or 5/8. If candidate D wins, the average load would be ((0 + 1/3) + (1/4 + 1/3) + (1/4 + 1/3)) / 3, or 1/2. Since 1/2 is the lowest average load, candidate D wins the second round.

Now everybody who voted for Candidate D has their load set to the average, 1/2 of all the loads.

Filled seats: 2 (B, D)
Open Seats: 1

Candidates: A B C D L0 L1 L2
---------------------------------
Voter V1: X 0 1/4 1/4
Voter V2: X X 0 0 1/2
Voter V3: X X 0 1/4 1/2
Voter V4: X X 0 1/4 1/4
Voter V5: X X X 0 1/4 1/2

There is now one seat open and two candidates, A and C. Voter V4 is the only one voting for A, so if A wins then the average load would be (1/4 + 1/1) / 1, or 5/4. Voters V2 and V5 (both with load 1/2) support C, so if C wins the average load would be ((1/2 + 1/2) + (1/2 + 1/2)) / 2, or 1. Since the average load would be lower with C, C wins the final seat.

Filled seats: 3 (B, D, C)
Open Seats: 0

Candidates: A B C D L0 L1 L2 L3
------------------------------------
Voter V1: X 0 1/4 1/4 1/4
Voter V2: X X 0 0 1/2 1
Voter V3: X X 0 1/4 1/2 1/2
Voter V4: X X 0 1/4 1/4 1/4
Voter V5: X X X 0 1/4 1/2 1

An interesting characteristic of this calculation is that the total load of all voters will always equal the number of seats filled in that round. In the zeroth round, load starts at 0 and there are no seats filled. After the first round, the total of all loads is 1, after the second round it is 2, etc.

Weighted Phragmén

Rationale

While this method works well if all voters have equal weight, this is not the case in Polkadot. Elections for both validators and candidates for the Council are weighted by the number of tokens held by the voters. This makes elections more similar to a corporate shareholder election than a traditional political election, where some members have more pull than others. Someone with a single token will have much less voting power than someone with 100. Although this may seem anti-democratic, in a pseudonymous system, it is trivial for someone with 100 tokens to create 100 different accounts and spread their wealth to all of their pseudonyms.

Therefore, not only do we want to allow voters to have their preferences expressed in the result, but do so while keeping as equal a distribution of their stake as possible and express the wishes of minorities as much as is possible. The Weighted Phragmén method allows us to reach these goals.

Algorithm

Weighted Phragmén is similar to Basic Phragmén in that it selects candidates sequentially, one per round, until the maximum number of candidates are elected. However, it has additional features to also allocate weight (stake) behind the candidates.

NOTE: in terms of validator selection, for the following algorithm, you can think of "voters" as "nominators" and "candidates" as "validators".

  1. Candidates are elected, one per round, and added to the set of successful candidates (they have won a "seat"). This aspect of the algorithm is very similar to the "basic Phragmén" algorithm described above.
  2. However, as candidates are elected, a weighted mapping is built, defining the weights of each selection of a validator by each nominator.

In more depth, the algorithm operates like so:

  1. Create a list of all voters, their total amount of stake, and which validators they support.
  2. Generate an initial edge-weighted graph mapping from voters to candidates, where each edge weight is the total potential weight (stake) given by that voter. The sum of all potential weight for a given candidate is called their approval stake.
  3. Now we start electing candidates. For the list of all candidates who have not been elected, get their score, which is equal to 1 / approval_stake.
  4. For each voter, update the score of each candidate they support by adding their total budget (stake) multiplied by the load of the voter and then dividing by that candidate's approval stake (voter_budget * voter_load / candidate_approval_stake).
  5. Determine the candidate with the lowest score and elect that candidate. Remove the elected candidate from the pool of potential candidates.
  6. The load for each edge connecting to the winning candidate is updated, with the edge load set to the score of the candidate minus the voter's load, and the voter's load then set to the candidate's score.
  7. If there are more candidates to elect, go to Step 3. Otherwise, continue to step 8.
  8. Now the stake is distributed amongst each nominator who backed at least one elected candidate. The backing stake for each candidate is calculated by taking the budget of the voter and multiplying by the edge load then dividing by the candidate load (voter_budget * edge_load / candidate_load).

Example

Note: All numbers in this example are rounded off to three decimal places.

In the following example, there are five voters and five candidates vying for three potential seats. Each voter V1 - V5 has an amount of stake equal to their number (e.g., V1 has stake of 1, V2 has stake of 2, etc.). Every voter is also going to have a load, which initially starts at 0.

Filled seats: 0
Open Seats: 3

Candidates: A B C D E L0
----------------------------
Voter V1 (1): X X 0
Voter V2 (2): X X 0
Voter V3 (3): X 0
Voter V4 (4): X X X 0
Voter V5 (5): X X 0

Let us now calculate the approval stake of each of the candidates. Recall that this is merely the amount of all support for that candidate by all voters.

Candidate A: 1 + 2 + 3 + 5 = 11
Candidate B: 1 + 2 + 4 = 7
Candidate C: 4 = 4
Candidate D: 4 + 5 = 9
Candidate E: 0

The first step is easy - candidate E has 0 approval stake and can be ignored from here on out. They will never be elected.

We can now calculate the initial scores of the candidates, which is 1 / approval_stake:

Candidate A: 1 / 11 = 0.091
Candidate B: 1 / 7 = 0.143
Candidate C: 1 / 4 = 0.25
Candidate D: 1 / 9 = 0.111
Candidate E: N/A

For every edge, we are going to calculate the score, which is current score plus the total budget * the load of the voter divided by the approval stake of the candidate. However, since the load of every voter starts at 0, and anything multiplied by 0 is 0, any addition will be 0 / x, or 0. This means that this step can be safely ignored for the initial round.

Thus, the best (lowest) score for Round 0 is Candidate A, with a score of 0.091.

Candidates:    A B C D E  L0 L1
----------------------------------
Voter V1 (1): X X 0 0.091
Voter V2 (2): X X 0 0.091
Voter V3 (3): X 0 0.091
Voter V4 (4): X X X 0 0
Voter V5 (5): X X 0 0.091
Filled seats: 1 (A)
Open Seats: 2

Candidates: A B C D E L0
----------------------------
Voter V1 (1): X X 0
Voter V2 (2): X X 0
Voter V3 (3): X 0
Voter V4 (4): X X X 0
Voter V5 (5): X X 0

Candidate A is now safe; there is no way that they will lose their seat. Before moving on to the next round, we need to update the scores on the edges of our graph for any candidates who have not yet been elected.

We elided this detail in the previous round, since it made no difference to the final scores, but we should go into depth here to see how scores are updated. We first must calculate the new loads of the voters, and then calculate the new scores of the candidates.

Any voter who had one of their choices for candidate fill the seat in this round (i.e., voters V1, V2, V3, and V5, who all voted for A) will have their load increased. This load increase will blunt the impact of their vote in future rounds, and the edge (which will be used in determining stake allocation later) is set to the score of the elected candidate minus the current voter load.

edge_load = elected_candidate_score - voter_load
voter_load = elected_candidate_score

In this instance, the score of the elected candidate is 0.091 and the voter loads are all 0. So for each voter who voted for A, we will calculate a new edge load Voter -> A of:

Edge load: 0.091 - 0 = 0.091

and a new voter load of:

Voter load: 0.091

As a reminder, here are the current scores. Loads of the voters are all 0.

Candidate B : 0.143
Candidate C : 0.25
Candidate D : 0.111

Now, we go through the weighted graph and update the score of the candidate and the load of the edge, using the algorithm:

candidate_score = candidate_score + ((voter_budget * voter_load) / candidate_approval_stake)

Without walking through each step, this gives us the following modifications to the scores of the different candidates.

V1 updates B to 0.156
V2 updates B to 0.182
V4 updates B to 0.182
V4 updates C to 0.25
V4 updates D to 0.111
V5 updates D to 0.162

After scores are updated, the final scores for the candidates for this round are:

Candidate B: 0.182
Candidate C: 0.25
Candidate D: 0.162

D, with the lowest score, is elected. You will note that even though candidate B had more voters supporting them, candidate D won the election due to their lower score. This is directly due to the fact that they had the lowest score, of course, but the root reason behind them having a lower score was both the greater amount of stake behind them and that voters who did not get one of their choices in an earlier round (in this example, voter V4) correspond to a higher likelihood of a candidate being elected.

We then update the loads for the voters and edges as specified above for any voters who voted for candidate D (viz., V4 and V5) using the same formula as above.

Filled seats: 2 (A, D)
Open Seats: 1

Candidates: A B C D E L0 L1 L2
-----------------------------------
Voter V1 (1): X X 0 0.091 0.091
Voter V2 (2): X X 0 0.091 0.091
Voter V3 (3): X 0 0.091 0.091
Voter V4 (4): X X X 0 0 0.162
Voter V5 (5): X X 0 0.091 0.162

Following a similar process for Round 2, we start with initial candidate scores of:

Candidate B : 0.143
Candidate C : 0.25

We can then update the scores of the remaining two candidates according to the algorithm described above.

V1 updates B to 0.156
V2 updates B to 0.182
V4 updates B to 0.274
V4 updates C to 0.412

With the lowest score of 0.274, Candidate B claims the last open seat. Candidates A, D, and B have been elected, and candidates C and E are not.

Before moving on, we must perform a final load adjustment for the voters and the graph.

Filled seats: 3 (A, D, B)
Open Seats: 0

Candidates: A B C D E L0 L1 L2 L3
------------------------------------------
Voter V1 (1): X X 0 0.091 0.091 0.274
Voter V2 (2): X X 0 0.091 0.091 0.274
Voter V3 (3): X 0 0.091 0.091 0.091
Voter V4 (4): X X X 0 0 0.162 0.274
Voter V5 (5): X X 0 0.091 0.162 0.162

Now we have to determine how much stake every voter should allocate to each candidate. This is done by taking the load of the each edge and dividing it by the voter load, then multiplying by the total budget of the voter.

In this example, the weighted graph ended up looking like this:

Nominator: V1
Edge to A load= 0.091
Edge to B load= 0.183
Nominator: V2
Edge to A load= 0.091
Edge to B load= 0.183
Nominator: V3
Edge to A load= 0.091
Nominator: V4
Edge to B load= 0.113
Edge to D load= 0.162
Nominator: V5
Edge to A load= 0.091
Edge to D load= 0.071

For instance, the budget of V1 is 1, the edge load to A is 0.091, and the voter load is 0.274. Using our equation:

backing_stake (A) = voter_budget * edge_load / voter_load

We can fill these variables in with:

backing_stake (A) = 1 * 0.091 / 0.274 = 0.332

For V1 backing stake of B, you can simply replace the edge load value and re-calculate.

backing_stake (B) = 1 * 0.183 / 0.274 = 0.668

Note that the total amount of all backing stake for a given voter will equal the total budget of the voter, unless that voter had no candidates elected, in which case it will be 0.

The final results are:

A is elected with stake 6.807.
D is elected with stake 4.545.
B is elected with stake 3.647.

V1 supports: A with stake: 0.332 and B with stake: 0.668.
V2 supports: A with stake: 0.663 and B with stake: 1.337.
V3 supports: A with stake: 3.0.
V4 supports: B with stake: 1.642 and D with stake: 2.358.
V5 supports: A with stake: 2.813 and D with stake: 2.187.

You will notice that the total amount of stake for candidates A, D, and B equals (aside from rounding errors) the total amount of stake of all the voters (1 + 2 + 3 + 4 + 5 = 15). This is because each voter had at least one of their candidates fill a seat. Any voter who had none of their candidates selected will also not have any stake in any of the elected candidates.

Optimizations

The results for nominating validators are further optimized for several purposes:

  1. To reduce the number of edges, i.e. to minimize the number of validators any nominator selects
  2. To ensure, as much as possible, an even distribution of stake among the validators
  3. Reduce the amount of block computation time

High-Level Description

After running the weighted Phragmén algorithm, a process is run that redistributes the vote amongst the elected set. This process will never add or remove an elected candidate from the set. Instead, it reduces the variance in the list of backing stake from the voters to the elected candidates. Perfect equalization is not always possible, but the algorithm attempts to equalize as much as possible. It then runs an edge-reducing algorithm to minimize the number of validators per nominator, ideally giving every nominator a single validator to nominate per era.

To minimize block computation time, the staking process is run as an off-chain worker. In order to give time for this off-chain worker to run, staking commands (bond, nominate, etc.) are not allowed in the last quarter of each era.

These optimizations will not be covered in-depth on this page. For more details, you can view the Rust implementation of elections in Substrate, the Rust implementation of staking in Substrate, or the seqPhragménwithpostprocessing method in the Python reference implementation. If you would like to dive even more deeply, you can review the W3F Research Page on Sequential Phragmén Method.

Rationale for Minimizing the Number of Validators Per Nominator

Paying out rewards for staking from every validator to all of their nominators can cost a non-trivial amount of chain resources (in terms of space on chain and resources to compute). Assume a system with 200 validators and 1000 nominators, where each of the nominators has nominated 10 different validators. Payout would thus require 1_000 * 10, or 10_000 transactions. In an ideal scenario, if every nominator selects a single validator, only 1_000 transactions would need to take place - an order of magnitude fewer. Empirically, network slowdown at the beginning of an era has occurred due to the large number of individual payouts by validators to nominators. In extreme cases, this could be an attack vector on the system, where nominators nominate many different validators with small amounts of stake in order to slow the system at the next era change.

While this would reduce network and on-chain load, being able to select only a single validator incurs some diversification costs. If the single validator that a nominator has nominated acts maliciously, then the nominator incurs a risk of a significant amount of slashing. Nominators are thus allowed to nominate up to 16 different validators. However, after the weighted edge-reducing algorithm is run, the number of validators per nominator is minimized. Nominators are likely to see themselves nominating a single active validator for an era.

At each era change, as the algorithm runs again, nominators are likely to have a different validator than they had before (assuming a significant number of selected validators). Therefore, nominators can diversify against incompetent or corrupt validators causing slashing on their accounts, even if they only nominate a single validator per era.

Rationale for Maintaining an Even Distribution of Stake

Another issue is that we want to ensure that as equal a distribution of votes as possible amongst the elected validators or council members. This helps us increase the security of the system by ensuring that the minimum amount of tokens in order to join the active validator set or council is as high as possible. For example, assume a result of five validators being elected, where validators have the following stake: {1_000, 20, 10, 10, 10}, for a total stake of 1_050. In this case, a potential attacker could join the active validator set with only 11 tokens, and could obtain a majority of validators with only 33 tokens (since the attacker only has to have enough stake to "kick out" the three lowest validators).

In contrast, imagine a different result with the same amount of total stake, but with that stake perfectly equally distributed: {210, 210, 210, 210, 210}. With the same amount of stake, an attacker would need to stake 633 tokens in order to get a majority of validators, a much more expensive proposition. Although obtaining an equal distribution is unlikely, the more equal the distribution, the higher the threshold - and thus the higher the expense - for attackers to gain entry to the set.

Rationale for Reducing Block Computing Time

Running the Phragmén algorithm is time-consuming, and often cannot be completed within the time limits of production of a single block. Waiting for calculation to complete would jeopardize the constant block production time of the network. Therefore, as much computation as possible is moved to an off-chain worker, which validators can work on the problem without impacting block production time.

To limit the complexity of the election and payout, any given nominator can only select a limited number of validators to nominate.

Phragmms (aka Balphragmms)

Phragmms, formerly known as Balphragmms, is a new election rule inspired by Phragmén and developed in-house for Polkadot. In general, election rules on blockchains is an active topic of research. This is due to the conflicting requirements for election rules and blockchains: elections are computationally expensive, but blockchains are computationally limited. Thus, this work constitutes state of the art in terms of optimization.

Proportional representation is a very important property for a decentralized network to have in order to maintain a sufficient level of decentralization. While this is already provided by the currently implemented seqPhragmen, this new election rule provides the advantage of the added security guarantee described below. As far as we can tell, at the time of writing, Polkadot and Kusama are the only blockchain networks that implement an election rule that guarantees proportional representation.

The security of a distributed and decentralized system such as Polkadot is directly related to the goal of avoiding overrepresentation of any minority. This is a stark contrast to traditional approaches to proportional representation axioms, which typically only seek to avoid underrepresentation.

Maximin Support Objective and PJR

This new election rule aims to achieve a constant-factor approximation guarantee for the maximin support objective and the closely related proportional justified representation (PJR) property.

The maximin support objective is based on maximizing the support of the least-supported elected candidate, or in the case of Polkadot and Kusama, maximizing the least amount of stake backing amongst elected validators. This security-based objective translates to a security guarantee for NPoS and makes it difficult for an adversarial whale’s validator nodes to be elected. The Phragmms rule, and the guarantees it provides in terms of security and proportionality, have been formalized in a peer-reviewed paper).

The PJR property considers the proportionality of the voter’s decision power. The property states that a group of voters with cohesive candidate preferences and a large enough aggregate voting strength deserve to have a number of representatives proportional to the group’s vote strength.

Comparing Sequential Phragmén, MMS, and Phragmms

Sequential Phragmén (seqPhragmen) and MMS are two efficient election rules that both achieve PJR.

Currently, Polkadot employs the seqPhragmen method for validator and council elections. Although seqPhramen has a very fast runtime, it does not provide constant-factor approximation for the maximin support problem. This is due to seqPhramen only performing an approximate rebalancing of the distribution of stake.

In contrast, MMS is another standard greedy algorithm that simultaneously achieves the PJR property and provides a constant factor approximation for maximin support, although with a considerably slower runtime. This is because for a given partial solution, MMS computes a balanced edge weight vector for each possible augmented committee when a new candidate is added, which is computationally expensive.

We introduce a new heuristic inspired by seqPhragmen, PhragMMS, which maintains a comparable runtime to seqPhragmen, offers a constant-factor approximation guarantee for the maximin support objective, and satisfies PJR. This is the fastest known algorithm to achieve a constant-factor guarantee for maximin support.

The New Election Rule: Phragmms

Phragmms is an iterative greedy algorithm that starts with an empty committee and alternates between the Phragmms heuristic for inserting a new candidate and rebalancing by replacing the weight vector with a balanced one. The main differentiator between Phragmms and seqPhragmen is that the latter only perform an approximate rebalancing. Details can be found in Balanced Stake Distribution.

The computation is executed by off-chain workers privately and separately from block production, and the validators only need to submit and verify the solutions on-chain. Relative to a committee A, the score of an unelected candidate c is an easy-to-compute rough estimate of what would be the size of the least stake backing if we added c to committee A. Observing on-chain, only one solution needs to be tracked at any given time, and a block producer can submit a new solution in the block only if the block passes the verification test, consisting of checking:

  1. Feasibility,
  2. Balance and
  3. Local Optimality - The least stake backing of A is higher than the highest score among unelected candidates

If the tentative solution passes the tests, then it replaces the current solution as the tentative winner. The official winning solution is declared at the end of the election window.

A powerful feature of this algorithm is the fact that both its approximation guarantee for maximin support and the above checks passing can be efficiently verified in linear time. This allows for a more scalable solution for secure and proportional committee elections. While seqPhragmen also has a notion of score for unelected candidates, Phragmms can be seen as a natural complication of the seqPhragmen algorithm, where Phragmms always grants higher score values to candidates and thus inserts them with higher support values.

To summarize, the main differences between the two rules are:

  • In seqPhragmen, lower scores are better, whereas in Phragmms, higher scores are better.
  • Inspired by seqPhragmen, the scoring system of Phragmms can be considered to be more intuitive and does a better job at estimating the value of adding a candidate to the current solution, and hence leads to a better candidate-selection heuristic.
  • Unlike seqPhragmen, in Phragmms, the edge weight vector w is completely rebalanced after each iteration of the algorithm.

The Phragmms election rule is currently being implemented on Polkadot. Once completed, it will become one of the most sophisticated election rules implemented on a blockchain. For the first time, this election rule will provide both fair representation (PJR) and security (constant-factor approximation for the maximin support objection) to a blockchain network.

Algorithm

The Phragmms algorithm iterates through the available seats, starting with an empty committee of size k:

  1. Initialize an empty committee A and zero edge weight vector w = 0.

  2. Repeat k times:

    • Find the unelected candidate with highest score and add it to committee A.
    • Re-balance the weight vector w for the new committee A.
  3. Return A and w.

External Resources